1
The Golden Age of
Social Science
Anastasia Buyalskaya
1
, Marcos Gallo
1
, Colin F. Camerer
1, 2
1
California Institute of Technology, Division of Humanities and Social Science
2
California Institute of Technology, Computational and Neural Systems
12 November 2019. Preliminary. Comments welcome. Corresponding author Anastasia
Buyalskaya (
abuyalsk@caltech.edu
).
1. Introduction
Social science is entering a golden age. A rise in effective interdisciplinarity, the
explosive growth of available data and computational power to make that data useful, and an
increasing realization that pressing social challenges require cooperation acr
oss disciplines, have
all contributed to this opportune time. Figure 1 presents evidence from cross
-
citations of how
interdisciplinary research is on the rise in some social sciences, although not uniformly. The
historically most inward
-
looking social sci
ence disciplines
--
psychology and economics,
according to the Figure 1 data
--
have become more open to the idea that researchers in
neighboring fields have important information and methods to contribute to their disciplines.
This opening of disciplinar
y borders is akin to an increasing “trade” of methods, languages, and
knowledge across fields.
The application of economic language about trade begins with the premise that, like
people and countries, each social science discipline has different “endowment
s” (e.g., historical
mastery of tools and accumulated knowledge) and comparative advantage (e.g., anthropologists
carefully study different parts of the world and economists develop formal models). Each
discipline has a specialized view, and none can fully
explain human nature on its own.
Economics is endowed with a set of formal mathematical tools that all graduate students must
master in order to make predictions based on optimization given preferences and beliefs, as well
as an econometrics toolkit for t
esting theories and inferring causation. Psychology explores the
rich web of cognitive and social mechanisms that generate individual beliefs and behaviors.
Anthropology seeks to understand cultural differences using ethnographic observation,
unearthing ph
ysical details of human development, and exploring mathematical models of co
-
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
2
evolution of culture and genes (among other approaches), hoping one model may effectively
approximate all human behavior at once. Political science studies systems of government,
voting,
juries, law, and a range of other situations in which people make consequential decisions
collectively. Finally, sociology investigates how the social world is created by and influences
how people think, feel, and act.
Figure 1: Changes in rates
of imported citations from neighboring disciplines from
1970 to 2015 for five social science disciplines. Imported citations are generally increasing
over this period, with notable exceptions (e.g., anthropology is not importing more citations
and is not
being imported either). Note the differences in y
-
axis ranges too: these show that
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
3
political science and sociology import a lot, but psychology and economics do not. The authors
used weighted citation rates to observe changes in citation rates from the fiv
e social sciences to
each of the other four. Plots are 5
-
year moving averages. Source:
Angrist et al. (2017
).
One of the challenges of interdisciplinary work is communication among researchers.
Multiple fields may investigate the same behavior but be unable to communicate their methods
in a manner digestible by all potential collaborators. Interdisciplinarity needs a common trade
language across disciplines, a “lingua franca.” In a useful lingua
franca, all disciplines adopt the
‘best’ language from whichever discipline first described an idea or construct with language
clear enough to be imported into a new discipline without much confusion. Working together to
build a common vocabulary will enh
ance the efficiency of trade and collaboration.
Prominent examples of lingua franca include rational choice theory from economics,
human laboratory experimental methods from psychology, culture from anthropology, survey
methods in political science, socia
l networks from sociology, and tools for causal inference from
all over. Another notable example is game theory. Created by mathematicians such as John
Nash, this framework only flourished after the seminal 1944 book by the polymath John von
Neumann and th
e economist Oskar Morgenstern. Game theory is a lingua franca for social
sciences because its basic concepts
--
players, information, strategies
--
are defined broadly enough
to potentially apply to genes, viruses, insects, animals, and organizations with shar
ed values,
including nation
-
states
(Gintis, 2007)
.
Most importantly, interdisciplinarity is necessary for solving complex multi
-
dimensional
problems and creating innovations for better health, w
ealth, and well
-
being
(Watts, 2017)
. Some
of today’s most significant and fastest
-
growing problems, such as drug addiction, obesity,
changes in political discourse, and climate change, cannot be
understood or solved by one
discipline alone. Instead, solving these issues will require an understanding of the institutional
incentives, cultural norms, cognitive mechanisms, and social network effects that created and
continue to heavily influence thes
e phenomena. Interdisciplinary work has already helped make
progress in fields, including poverty, health epidemics, and mental health.
Drug trafficking is one such example of how an interdisciplinary approach can facilitate
problem
-
solving.
Magliocca et al. (2019)
combined interdisciplinarity and new data to analyze
international drug trafficking in Central America (Figure 2). The researchers tested an agent
-
based model against a dat
abase of estimated illicit drug flows from 2000
-
2014. In their model,
the agents were local suppliers, cartel networks, and interdiction organizations trying to intercept
drugs from the traffickers. The traffickers were motivated by profit, including a pri
ced
-
in
interdiction risk premium. Interdiction agents were motivated to intercept drugs (and interdiction
capacity increased based on past success). Agent
-
based models seek to derive complex, lifelike
behavior that is “emergent” from interactions of simple
agents, typically simulating behavior
which is too complex to solve mathematically. The model is successful at capturing many of the
underlying trends, across time and countries, in trafficking flow and interdiction. It reproduces
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
4
two effects known as the
“balloon” effect (when trafficking spreads into new areas) and the
“cockroach” effect (when trafficking routes become fragmented).
Figure 2: Central America modeling domain (center) with an example simulated narco
-
trafficking network consisting of inac
tive nodes (gray circles), active nodes (red circles), and
trafficking routes between each active node (dashed lines). The most southern and northern
nodes outside of the model domain represent supply (e.g., Colombia) and demanding nodes
(e.g., Mexico), re
spectively. Around the periphery, comparisons of subnational cocaine
shipment volumes (blue regions in the map) reported at the administrative level of departments
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
5
in the Consolidated Counterdrug Database (CCDB) (red line) and median volumes simulated
by m
odel versions with (blue line) and without (black line) a Network Agent. Shaded regions
represent the bounds of the second and third quartiles of simulated cocaine volumes.
Departments were selected to include at least one location per country and on the b
asis of
having at least 5 y of continuous observations reported in CCDB. Image and legend from
(Magliocca et al., 2019)
.
This study illustrates practice and promise in the golden age in many w
ays. First, their
team consists of nine co
-
authors from seven universities, one government organization, and a
coauthor who remained anonymous to protect confidential sources (and perhaps to stay alive).
Their affiliations span geography, politics, biology
, and earth sciences. Second, their model
includes a novel application of ideas from behavioral economics about learning
(Camerer & Ho,
1999)
and salience
(Bordalo, Gennaioli, & Shleifer, 2012)
of specific trafficking events. Third,
their model can be used to analyze how different policies will hypothetically change trafficking,
prices, and drug use. Of course, models like this are nev
er perfect, but they are a starting point
and can always be improved using new evidence and plausible extensions.
In the next section, we present two more general “case studies” of successful
interdisciplinarity
--
behavioral economics and social network science. In both cases,
interdisciplinary research led to the creation of new cross
-
disciplinary fields of inquiry b
uilt on
the comparative advantages of contributing fields, inspiring a shared lingua franca, generating
insights about human nature, and improving social outcomes.
2. Case Study: Behavioral Economics
Behavioral economics is the first of our t
wo examples of successful interdisciplinary
enterprises
(Thaler, 2015, 2018)
. Behavioral economics uses evidence and methods from other
social sciences
--
particularly psychology
--
to analyze n
atural limits on human computation,
willpower, and selfishness. These analyses make new predictions about natural field data,
including how markets work and can make novel suggestions about policies to improve human
welfare.
Analyzing such limits was of in
terest because conventional rational choice theory
assumes maximization of subjective values (“utilities”) and Bayesian integration of information,
sometimes over a long
-
time horizon or accounting correctly for risks. Not all people are always
that smart o
r patient.
To be fair, rational choice theory was always intended to be useful, rather than realistic.
The question behavioral economists tackled was whether theories assuming more realistic
psychology could be precise and
more
useful. Thaler and others
(Camerer, Loewenstein, &
Rabin, 2004)
used an “insider” approach. This insider approach took rational choice theory as a
simple benchmark, identified empirical “anomalies” that could not be sensi
bly explained by that
benchmark, and sought explanations which added extra ingredients sparingly, to explain the
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
6
anomalies and make new predictions. The first step was to begin with highly controlled
laboratory experimental evidence (using hybrid methods f
rom psychology and experimental
economics) to convince skeptics and establish plausible alternative theories. Then we turned to
make new predictions about field data. Alternative theories with a small number of added
parameters were developed so that ratio
nal and behavioral predictions could be compared
(DellaVigna, 2018)
.
Example #1: Loss aversion.
In their influential prospect theory,
Kahneman
and
Tversky (1979, 1992)
proposed that
outcomes were subjectively valued by their gains and losses relative
to a reference point,
analogous to how a single percept could be subjectively perceived
--
or “framed”
--
as one of two
distinct things (such as the face
-
vase illusion). For example, people may estimate their longevity
to be higher if they judge the chance
that they would live to age 75, compared to when they
judged the chance that they would die before age 75
(Payne, Sagara, Shu, Appelt, & Johnson,
2013)
.
Tversky and Kahneman also suggested that
losses were disliked much more than equal
-
sized gains, a phenomenon called “loss
-
aversion.” Loss
-
aversion is sometimes conveniently
expressed by a single parameter,
λ
, the ratio of gain utilities to loss utilities (or to their marginal
utilities), which i
s often measured to be around 1.9 (Figure 2b).
Loss
-
aversion became part of explanations for many different phenomena in social
science, such as (1) which kinds of financial risks people accept or dislike in lab experiments
(Gneezy & Potters, 1997)
, (2) why stocks return so much more than bonds
(Thaler & Benartzi,
2004)
, and (3) why there is a gap between high prices demanded to sell
goods and lower prices
paid to buy the same goods, the “endowment effect”
(Kahneman, Knetsch, & Thaler, 1990)
.
Psychologists demonstrated how sadness and disgust change the endowment effect
(Lerner,
Small, & Loewenstein, 2004)
and also suggested effects of cognitive sequencing
(Johnson,
Häubl, & Keinan, 2007)
and attention
(Bhatia & Golman, 2019; Yechiam & Hochman, 2013)
.
Cognitive neuroscientists have found evidence for loss
-
aversion in neural circuitry
(Tom, Fox,
Trepel, & Poldrack, 2007)
, including dissociations between circuitry valuing gains and losses
(Yacubian et al., 2006)
and an unusual
tolerance
of losses in patients with amygdala dam
age
(De
Martino, Camerer, & Adolphs, 2010)
. Political scientists have posited loss
-
aversion as one
reason why concessions in bargaining are difficult
(McDermott, 2004)
and have analyzed its
theoretical effects on election outcomes
(Alesina & Passarelli, 2019)
and trade policy
(Tovar,
2009)
. Figure 2 illustrates estimates of loss
-
aversion along with applications from goal
-
setting at
round numbers and “narrow bracketing” of local losses and gains that should, rationally, be
added up.
Many behavioral economists have
not been keenly interested in the evolutionary and
cultural origins of phenomena like loss
-
aversion (an unfortunate omission, in our view). There is
evidence that loss
-
aversion and endowment effects are present in monkeys
(Lakshminaryanan,
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
7
Chen, & Santos, 2008)
and great apes
(Kanngiesser, Santos, Hood, & Call, 2011)
--
though only
for food and not for other valued goods (e.g., tools).
Apicella, Azevedo, Christakis
and
Fowler
(2014)
also found an unusual
lack of endowment effects among market
-
isolated Hadza villagers
in Tanzania. These data indicate that loss
-
aversion is not as universal as thought, and show why a
wider scope of new data is needed.
Figure 2: Loss
-
Aversion. (a) The gain
-
loss utility function over money derived from group
parameters estimated from risky choices
(Baillon, Bleichrodt, & Spinu, 2018)
. (b) The
empirical distribu
tion of the loss
-
aversion parameter
λ
from a meta
-
analysis. The blue and red
panels include 286 and 469 effects, respectively (unpublished author data). (c) The
distribution of marathon finishing times, with over nine million data points
(Allen, Dechow,
Pope, & Wu, 2017)
. Note the peaks at round numbers. (d) Actual point values in each period,
plotted against optimal conditional point values from consumption choices, in a 50
-
period
savings experi
ment
(Brown, Chua, & Camerer, 2009)
. Note how few actual point values are
negative even when optimal point values should be negative. This indicates that most subjects
do not like to make choice
s that generate individual
-
period losses (“narrow bracketing”), even
though performance is determined by the sum of all 50 periods.
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
8
Loss
-
aversion contributes to a “status quo bias,” the exaggerated tendency to choose a
suggested default (or a previous st
atus quo) when other choices are readily available
(Samuelson
& Zeckhauser, 1988)
. Countries in which organ donation is the default have much higher rates of
donation than those in which it is n
ot the default, even though the choice is simple to make
(Johnson & Goldstein, 2003)
. The first impactful application of status quo bias is the “Save More
Tomorrow” (SMART) plan
(Thaler & Benartzi, 2004)
. In this plan, companies auto
-
enroll
workers into tax
-
advantaged 401(k) plans and invest a fraction of their next pay raise into the
plan (so their paycheck does not go down and create
s a subjective loss). These plans have
increased savings substantially, with no apparent reduction in savings from other sources
(Chetty, Friedman, Leth
-
Petersen, Nielsen, & Olsen, 2014)
. The SM
ART plan became a poster
child for many types of “nudges,” designed choices that help some people make better decisions
than they are likely to make on their own
(Camerer, Issacharoff, Loewenste
in, O’Donoghue, &
Rabin, 2003; Thaler & Sunstein, 2009)
.
Example #2: Social preferences
Humans are the most prosocial species
--
helping unrelated others at a cost to ourselves
--
and we alsoe create large
-
scale institutions to facilitate such prosocial behavior. Cutting across
social sciences is the question of how to express this prosociality m
athematically, and what data
to collect. Behavioral economics contributed both theories and a menu of economic choices and
games.
Of course, prosociality has long been contemplated in all social sciences, as well as in
biology, moral philosophy, literatur
e, and beyond. In economics, Adam Smith discussed “moral
sentiments” and “fellow
-
feeling”
(Smith, 1759)
. In 1881, Edgeworth included a “coefficient of
effective sympathy”
--
the weight one person
places on the utility of another
--
to try to make
bargaining theory more precise
(Edgeworth, 1881)
. That simple formulation and other variants
(Loewenstein, Thompson, & Bazerman, 1989)
are still used today. In the 1960s, social
psychologists began to describe social value orientations in the style of psychometrics
(Messick
&
McClintock, 1968)
and distinguished importantly between equal outcomes and equitable ones,
reflecting differences in need or inputs
(Messick & Cook, 1983)
.
Game theory offers canonical strategi
c interactions that can be used to dissect elements of
prosociality. A famous example is the “ultimatum game”
(Camerer, 2003; Güth, Schmittberger,
& Schwarze, 1982)
. In this game, a proposer off
ers a share of a known amount of resources, such
as $10, to a responder. The responder can accept the offer, in which case bargaining ends and
they collect their money, or the responder can reject it, and then they both get zero. Games like
this can measu
re whether and why people will reject money and whether the proposer correctly
anticipates rejection.
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
9
Rejecting a low ultimatum offer is now thought to show negative reciprocity
--
a
willingness to sacrifice resources to harm another person who has been unf
air (relative to a social
norm, often with cultural content). This tendency is even evident at the collective level. For
example, police effectively solve fewer criminal cases after losing a wage arbitration
(Mas,
2006)
.
As the ultimatum game caught on across social sciences, other fascinating games quickly
followed, each with a natural interpretation about psychological motives
(Cam
erer & Fehr,
2004)
: (1) dictator allocations, in which the responder must accept the offer (measuring altruism
and norm
-
sensitivity); (2) trust games, in which a first
-
mover invests money, with a social risk to
potentially benefit both parties, gambling th
at the second
-
mover will share the total gain
(Berg,
Dickhaut, & McCabe, 1995; Camerer & Weigelt, 1988)
; and (3) many
-
person gift
-
exchange
labor markets in which firms prepay wages and hope that
workers exert costly effort which
benefits the firms and repays their trust
(DellaVigna & Pope, 2018; Ernst Fehr, Kirchsteiger, &
Riedl, 1993)
.
Anthropologists also adopted these games. An interdisciplinary team, including
anthropologists and behavioral economists, used economic games to study cross
-
cultural
sociality in small
-
scale societies
(Henrich et al., 2005, 2010)
. They learned that stronger sharing
norms (which were punished by ultimatum rejections) were associated with societal cooperation,
such as, building houses together, and with the extent of market trading.
As interest in
these games grew, the sociological lingua franca of a “norm” got imported
into other social sciences. Norms are informal social rules that are expected to be followed, and
usually informally self
-
enforced by social punishment for deviations (even absent le
gal
enforcement). In dictator allocation games, for example, people have different subjective norms
about what is fair to share. Their sharing of actual money is closely tied to their norm perceptions
(Krupka & Weber, 2009)
. Thus, sharing money seems to reflect “manners” consistent with
perceived norms rather than altruism per se
(Camerer & Thaler, 1995)
.
Cognitive neuroscientists have also used these games to measure social preferences,
identify circuitry implementing prosociality
(Tricomi, Rangel, Camerer, & O’Doherty, 2010)
,
associate brain le
sions with abnormal social preference
(Krajbich, Adolphs, Tranel, Denburg, &
Camerer, 2009)
, and linking to individual differences in neurotypical populations more generally
(Bruhin, Fehr, & Schunk, 2019)
.
Knowing more about social preferences has not contributed immediately to solving social
problems at the scale that “nudging” has. However, experiments have suggested social forces
t
hat could enhance prosociality. For example, allowing people to punish others who have
behaved antisocially seems to increase cooperation
(Fehr & Gächter, 2000; Yamagishi, 1986)
,
although the re
sults vary culturally
(Herrmann, Thoni, & Gächter, 2008)
. New evidence has also
invigorated understanding of charitable giving
(Dell
aVigna, List, & Malmendier, 2012)
. In the
future, diagnostic tools will likely emerge from a better understanding of sociality, with
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
10
applications ranging from psychiatry, methods to develop empathy, and people analytics
enhancing the matching of workers wi
th jobs.
Summary:
Progress in understanding loss
-
aversion and social preferences in behavioral economics
(and many intellectually neighboring fields) are two example illustrations of how
interdisciplinarity and better measurement create progress and ev
en help solve problems
,
in our
golden age. The simple idea of loss
-
aversion came from perceptual psychology and compelling
early data. There was substantial hostility to the idea of loss
-
aversion in mainstream economics
for many years. The idea that people
have preferences over what others get, familiar within
social psychology, was less controversial, but there is still debate about the best general theory.
In general, behavioral economists won over skeptics by weaponizing the mantra that ‘the
easiest way
to win an argument is to run another experiment or another statistical regression’
(Thaler, 2018)
. In many areas of behavioral economics and finance, large data sets played an
important role, i
ncluding more recently, multi
-
site lab and field experiments
(Cohn, Maréchal,
Tannenbaum, & Zünd, 2019; Herrmann et al. 2008)
. A treasure trove of experimental data came
about as nudges and othe
r ideas were implemented by “behavioral insight teams” in firms, and
governments on every continent, currently just over 200, according to the OECD
(“Behavioural
insights
—
OECD,” n.d.)
to create better outcomes for citizens and consumers (Halpern 2015).
As noted in discussing loss
-
aversion above, there has been limited interest of many
behavioral economists in the deeper biological and cultural origins of preferences, norms, and
c
ognitive limits. Such data and models are necessary to generalize ideas beyond activity in
developed societies that are “WEIRD”
(Henrich et al., 2005)
and not representative of all human
activit
y. How preferences are formed and changed is also central to essential discussions about
the value of economic institutions, like market development
(Bowles & Polanía
-
Reyes, 2012)
.
3. Case Stud
y: Social Networks
Social networks are our second example of successful interdisciplinary enterprises. Network
analysis uses methods from physics, computer science, and applied math to analyze questions
often studied by sociologists, anthropologists, and
psychologists regarding how interpersonal
relationships are formed and how behaviors, beliefs, and emotions are transmitted across
connected individuals
(Watts & Dodds, 2007)
. One striking featu
re of network analysis is the
diversity of scholars contributing to intellectual progress. People from different fields, traditions,
and countries have worked together on related questions
(Free
man, 2004)
. Network analysis has
been significantly enabled by the availability of novel datasets, such as social media connections
as well as increasingly “connected” devices, such as fitness trackers with social aspects
(Aral &
Nicolaides, 2017; Coviello et al., 2014; Phan & Airoldi, 2015)
.
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
11
The recent history of network analysis owes a lot to
Watts & Strogatz (1998)
, who highlighte
d
several key network properties, including that real networks are neither totally ordered nor
random. However, it turned out that simple mathematical models could capture features of
complex networks, and those models could be applied to network dynamics
across a variety of
phenomena. It turns out that the seemingly unrelated affiliations between actors, power grid
transmission lines, and the neural network of
C. elegans
could all be captured via a simple
“small
-
world” network model, a mathematical graph i
n which the nodes (individuals) are not
neighbors with most of the other nodes, and yet all other nodes can be reached in a small number
of steps (limited degrees of freedom connecting individuals)
(Christakis & Fowler, 2011;
Jackson, 2019; Watts, 2003, 2004)
.
Figure 3: (a) A network of human traffic reveals cities that are important nodes (in
yellow) and effective borders (in red)
(Thiemann, Theis, Grady, Brune, & Brockmann, 2010)
.
(b) A network of international financial institutions. Edges symbolize mutual share
-
holdings
(Schweitzer et al., 2009)
. Note the high connectivity among nodes that can create systemic risk
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
12
and network vulnerability. (c) Effects of the distribution of sexual partner concurrency on
network connectivity
(adapted from Morris, Goodreau, & Moody, 2008)
. Note how a slight
increase in average concurrent partners (from the top left to right histograms) dramatically
impacts the number of nodes in the largest component of the network. (
d) A network of brain
regions where edges represent developmental increases in streamline density
(Baker et al.,
2015)
.
Example #1: Spread of Infectious Disease
Sociologists have been int
egral to guiding the development of these network models, given how
ubiquitously they can help explain the spread of anything from disease to innovation
(Davis &
Greve, 1997)
. Most infectious di
seases spread through human contact, making the study of
infection a natural place to apply network analysis. One of the first and longest
-
used models of
disease spread, known as the
SIR model
, was introduced by
Kermack & McKendrick (1927)
and
included some highly oversimplified assumptions, including that individuals of different classes
(i.e., infected vs. susceptible) connected exclusively in pairs, an
d that those connections occurred
randomly.
As recounted by Martina Morris, it was feedback from a man in Uganda which illuminated the
severe limitation of a model unable to handle multiple connections (multiple sexual partners) at
once
–
something which is still closer to the norm than the exceptio
n in several societies
(Kretzschmar & Morris, 1996)
. This insight led Morris and collaborators to create better models,
ones which more accurately explained how the AIDS epidemic was spreading
–
specifically,
how small variations in concurrency (simultaneous sexual partners) could have dramatic effects
on a population’s vulnerability to HIV
(Morris & Kretzschmar, 1997)
.
It is unclear
whether concurrency explains the full story, given that empirically it does not
explain why places with high rates of concurrency do not necessarily have high rates of HIV and
vice versa. One response to this is the potential misreporting regarding sexual
activity, a private
matter that complicates accurate data collection. Morris’s team continues to collaborate across
disciplines (with sociologists and statisticians
–
she is a professor of both), as well as across
geographies (with several collaborators i
n Africa), to refine and improve models of the spread of
infection, and apply them to new and better datasets.
Example #2: Revisiting Influence and Information Transmission
Several social science disciplines, from anthropology to political science, are
particularly
interested in collective decision making. While often studied at a static point in time, implicitly
assuming that all individuals simultaneously make independent decisions, the heterogeneous
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
13
process of information accumulation and integration
prior to decision making suggests that
decisions are actually made sequentially and that beliefs can be similarly “transmitted” from one
individual to the next. The field of cultural evolution has been modeling information
transmission for several decades
, using both epidemiological and social network models in their
approach
(Richerson & Boyd, 1989)
.
Broadly,
social contagion models allow simulating the speed at which individuals receive
information and how past interactions influence their behavior
(Watts & Dodds, 2007)
. These
models focus on a hand
ful of key parameters, which can be grouped as: (1) degree centrality, (2)
eigenvector centrality, (3) diffusion centrality, and (4) bridging
(Jackson, 2019)
. While one
might
not
wish to be cent
ral in an HIV infection network, centrality is viewed as an advantage in
most social networks and is correlated with financial success
(Burt & Ronchi, 2007)
and well
-
being
(Morelli, Ong, Makati, Jackson, & Zaki, 2017)
. Degree centrality captures “popularity,”
the sheer number of connections an individual might have, capturing the speed at which these
individuals can easily transmit inf
ormation to a wide group at once. Eigenvector centrality,
which captures how many well
-
connected others one is connected to, has been used to study
social status and scapegoats
(Weaverdyck & Par
kinson, 2018)
. Diffusion centrality is a measure
of “reach,” capturing how well
-
positioned an individual is to spread and hear about information.
Finally, bridging captures “social chameleons” who connect otherwise disparate groups.
Interestingly, all of t
hese positions appear to be context general: if an individual is central in one
network, they are likely to be central in another, and so forth
(Jackson, 2019)
.
Network analysis has therefore a
llowed researchers to apply new tools while revisiting old
questions about social influence. For example, researchers have investigated whom individuals
gravitate to in a network, finding that empathetic people are chosen for situations which require
trust
and support, while positive people are chosen for situations that are fun and exciting
(Morelli et al., 2017). Other work has found that people give less money to those who are more
socially distant (unknown) friends of friends in standard economic games
(Candelo, Eckel, &
Johnson, 2018; Goeree, McConnell, Mitchell, Tromp, & Yariv, 2010)
. Computational modeling
methods have also been used to show that there is quicker consolidation of majority
opinion and
more successful spread of initially unpopular beliefs in populations characterized by their greater
susceptibility to social influence
(Muthukrishna & Schaller, 2019)
.
Given how ma
ny behaviors
–
from smoking to divorce
–
are “contagious” across individuals, the
dynamics of such contagion are of immense interest to social scientists and non
-
social scientists
alike.
Summary:
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
14
Network science would have been less successful without sc
ientists from different disciplines
borrowing ideas and communicating in a shared language about constructs and methods. To take
a meta
-
perspective, innovation in network science has benefited from the wide network of
researchers who share a lingua franca,
can transmit high fidelity information, and bring a
diversity of perspectives to the table (Muthukrishna & Henrich 2016).
Networks and their properties are fundamentally interesting because they underpin such a wide
range of phenomena. Unlike behavioral
economics, there was less conflict among those studying
networks because the concept of a network was so obviously appealing and useful from the start
(i.e., there was no interdisciplinary conflict about whether people “were networked” as occurred
about w
hether people “were rational”). Furthermore, while sociologists studied networks first,
the difficult question of what networks arise when people have scarce social bandwidth and can
choose network links was cracked by economists
(Jackson & Wolinsky, 1996)
. Moreover, the
increasing availability of large, novel datasets that capture connections between individuals, such
as social media and online communication data, has truly turbo
-
charged network
science.
4. Spotlight on Studies
Table 1 displays twelve studies that epitomize the golden age of social science research
(Salganik, 2018)
. Each of these papers is an excellent example of one or more of these features:
(1) collaborating in an interdisciplinary team; (2) using new types of data; and (3) answering
important and difficult questions. The table also demonstrates a wide variety o
f research topics,
from exercise habits and social inequality to political preferences; and a diversity of datasets,
including genetics, brain imaging, and browsing history. One notable study using CCTV footage
tests the long
-
lived belief from early social
psychology experiments that bystanders do not
intervene to help strangers if there are other bystanders around (they actually do).
Summary
Subfield(s)*
Main Novelty
Reference
Evolutionary changes
in hominins created a
niche that favored
individuals with the
ability to
communicate and
persuade,
transforming
sociopolitical life.
Anthropology,
Political Science
Interdisciplinarity
(Gintis, van Schaik,
& Boehm, 2015)
Greater exposure to
war increases
Anthropology,
Biology, Economics
Interdisciplinarity
(Henrich, Bauer,
Cassar, Chytilová, &
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
15
religiosity.
Purzycki, 2019)
Rwandans use the
mobile phone
network to transfer
“mobile money” to
those affected by
unexpected economic
shocks.
Economics
New type of data:
mobile phone usage
(Blumenstock,
Fafchamps, & Eagle,
2011)
Describing the
barriers to
understanding the
impact of AI on the
labor market.
Economics
Interdisciplinarity
(
Frank et al., 2019
)
Railroad expansion
from 1870 to 1890 in
the U.S. increased
agricultural land
value.
Economic History
New type of data:
geographic
information system
network database
(Donaldson &
Hornbeck, 2016)
Brain responses to
emotionally evocative
images predict
political ideology.
Polit
ical Science,
Neuroscience,
Psychiatry
Interdisciplinarity,
new type of data:
fMRI
(Ahn et al., 2014)
Genetic data can
predict economic and
political preferences.
Political Science,
Economics,
Psychology,
Sociology
Interdisciplinarity,
new type of data:
GWAS
(Benjamin et al.,
2012)
Musical preferences
and personality traits
are linked.
Psychology,
Market
ing
New type of data:
Facebook likes
(Nave et al., 2018)
Bystanders will help
in public conflict.
Psychology,
Sociology
Interdisciplinarity,
new type of data:
CCTV footage
(Philpot, Liebst,
Levine, Bernasco, &
Lindegaard, 2019)
Social networks
strongly influence
exercise habits.
Sociology
New type of data:
fitness tracking
(Aral & Nicolaides,
2017)
Fatal shootings of
police officers
increases police
Sociology
New type of data:
NYC stop
-
and
-
frisk
reports
(Legewie, 2016)
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
16
violence towards
black suspects.
Estimating social,
environmental, and
health inequalities
with neural networks
and street images.
Sociology,
Economics
New type of data:
street images
(Suel, Polak, Bennett,
& E
zzati, 2019)
*As much as we admire those who cross disciplinary boundaries, making it difficult to identify
home fields, authors’ departmental affiliations are used here as a heuristic description.
5. Conclusion and Challenges
Interdisciplinary research inevitably presents new challenges. The following obstacles are worth
noting given they disproportionately concern teams working on questions that cut across
disciplines. It is advised that interdisciplinary research teams discus
s and plan for dealing with
these challenges before the research work begins:
·
The question of
informatics
, or where and how information is accumulated, can be
a special challenge for teams who are used to contributing to traditionally disparate
di
sciplines. Many journals cater to the readership of a specific discipline or discipline
subfield, with authors citing papers predominantly from like
-
minded journals. While
cross
-
citation is on the rise, it is not guaranteed that interdisciplinary work will
make
equal contributions across fields, presenting the possibility of losing valuable insight
with relevance to one of the fields.
·
Closely tied to informatics is the question of
incentives and authorship
.
Academics are often encouraged to remain f
ocused on contributing to their respective
subject areas, which means working with other academics in the same subfield and
publishing in a specialized set of journals. While often practical and well
-
meaning
advice, it constrains people to narrow paths wit
h little upside to taking on
interdisciplinary ventures. Furthermore, differences in authorship norms across
disciplines (such as the strong emphasis on solo
-
authored papers in economics) make
young researchers reluctant to join projects where a bigger tea
m size is necessary in
order to capture the range of specialized contributions necessary to tackle big research
questions. If interdisciplinary work is to take off truly, research which makes
contributions to other fields cannot be discounted, and papers w
ith multiple co
-
authors
should not automatically be seen as a smaller contribution than single
-
authored work.
·
Interdisciplinarity possesses unique challenges for
“open science”
--
i.e., the sharing
of procedures, data, and code intended to make res
earch more widely accessible
--
because different social science disciplines often have different tools and norms. As
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
17
Stodden et al. (2016) note, “Current reporting methods are often uneven, incomplete, and
still evolving.” However, this challenge is now wi
dely recognized, and efforts are
underway to improve open science in practice.
·
As mentioned in the introduction, interdisciplinary teams tend to work on big
questions, applying a range of tools and insights to solve important, complex problems.
A ch
aracteristic feature of these problems is their tendency to bring up novel concerns
regarding individual
privacy and ethics
. New types of data
–
from genetics to real
-
time
biofeedback
–
carry potentially sensitive information. Sensors have great promise fo
r
changing behavior and mitigating risk as a real
-
time physical nudge. However, they also
present ethical quandaries, such as what happens if the sensors make a mistake or the
nudge is overridden. Scientists take experimentation and transparency for grante
d, but
the average citizen is more skeptical
(Meyer et al., 2019)
. Interdisciplinary teams across
social science should seek ethicists and legal scholars to join the conversation.
·
Anoth
er challenge is the creation of
unifying frameworks
to explain behaviors
across disciplines. Better theories will restrain the number of explanations that could be
derived from big data by setting appropriate priors for hypotheses (Muthukrishna &
Henrich,
2019). An expansion of methodological approaches alone will not increase
scientific knowledge unless there is common lingua franca or, even better, genuinely
unifying frameworks. Akin to the construction of modern biology from unifying
principles in chemi
stry and physics, social science would benefit from evolutionarily
plausible theories that provide ultimate (function) and proximate (mechanism)
explanations.
(Gintis, 2007)
makes an argument that game theory is one promising
candidate for unification.
The challenges of informatics, incentives, open science, ethics, and theoretical unification
are serious. However, the same interdisciplinarity, creation of institutions, and
reliance on better
and more extensive data that make for our golden age should help solve these challenges too.
Furthermore, there is reason to be optimistic: our increasingly connected age means that
knowledge from other disciplines is much easier to acce
ss. Cross
-
disciplinary citations no longer
require walking between libraries to find journals siloed in between the literal four walls of their
own field!
It is foolish, of course, to forecast both a number and a time at which problems like the
worldwide
rise of obesity or “fake news” will be reined in. However, it is safe to say that our
golden age will be marked by faster rates of progress in producing breakthrough social science
and solutions to such human suffering than ever before.
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
18
Acknowledgments
: We thank Fred Blum, Jonathan Katz, Joseph Henrich, Philip Hoffman, Scott
Page, and Jerry Davis for helpful comments and discussions on related concepts in social
science. We are grateful for the support of the T&C Chen Center (Fellowships for MG and AB,
support for CFC), the Behavioral and Neuroeconomics Discovery Fund (for CFC), and
especially Trilience (for CFC) for a longstanding interest in, and financial support of this topic.
Works Cited
Ahn, W.
-
Y., Kishida, K. T., Gu, X., Lohrenz, T., Harvey, A., Alford, J. R., ... Montague, P. R. (2014).
Nonpolitical Images Evoke Neural Predictors of Political Ideology.
Current Biology
,
24
(22),
2693
–
2699. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2014.09.050
Alesina, A., & Passarelli, F. (2019). Loss Aversion in Politics.
American Journal of Political Science
.
https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12440
Allen, E. J., Dechow, P. M., Pope, D. G., & Wu, G. (2017). Reference
-
Dependent Preferences: Evidence
from Marathon Runners.
Management Science
,
63
(6), 1657
–
1672.
https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2417
Angrist, J., Azoulay, P., Ellison, G., Hill, R., & Lu, S. F. (2017). Inside Job
or Deep Impact? Using
Extramural Citations to Assess Economic Scholarship.
Journal of Economic Literature
.
https://doi.org/10.3386/
w23698
Apicella, C. L., Azevedo, E. M., Christakis, N. A., & Fowler, J. H. (2014). Evolutionary Origins of the
Endowment Effect: Evidence from Hunter
-
Gatherers.
American Economic Review
,
104
(6), 1793
–
18
05. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.6.1793
Aral, S., & Nicolaides, C. (2017). Exercise contagion in a global social network.
Nature
Communications
,
8
(1), 14753. https://doi.org/10.1038/ncomms14753
Baillon, A., Bleichrodt, H., & Spinu, V. (2018).
Searching for the Reference Point
[Working Paper].
Retrieved from https://aurelienbaillon.com/research/papers/pdf/reference_point.pdf
Baker, S. T. E., Lubman, D. I., Yucel, M., Allen, N. B., Whittle, S., Fulcher, B. D., ... Fornito, A. (2015).
Developmental Changes in Brain Network Hub Connectivity in Late Adolescence.
Journal o
f
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
19
Neuroscience
,
35
(24), 9078
–
9087. https://doi.org/10.1523/JNEUROSCI.5
043
-
14.2015
Behavioural insights
—
OECD. (n.d.). Retrieved August 28, 2019, from Organisation for Economics Co
-
operation and Development website: https://www.oecd.org/gov/regulatory
-
policy/behavio
ural
-
insights.htm
Benjamin, D. J., Cesarini, D., van der Loos, M. J. H. M., Dawes, C. T., Koellinger, P. D., Magnusson, P.
K. E., ... Visscher, P. M. (2012). The genetic architecture of economic a
nd political preferences.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
,
109
(21), 8026
–
8031.
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1120666109
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, Reciprocity, an
d Social History.
Games and
Economic Behavior
,
10
(1), 122
–
142. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.1995.1027
Bhatia, S., & Golman, R. (2019). Attention and reference dependence.
Decision
,
6
(2), 145
–
170.
https://doi.org/10.1037/dec0000094
Blumenstock, J. E., Fafchamps, M., & Eagle, N. (2011). Risk and Reciprocity Over the Mobile Phone
Network: Evidence from Rwanda.
SSRN Electronic Journal
.
https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1958042
Bordalo, P., Gennaioli,
N., & Shleifer, A. (2012). Salience theory of choice under risk.
The Quarterly
Journal of Economics
,
127
(3), 1243
–
1285.
Bowles, S., & Polanía
-
Reyes, S. (2012). Economic Incentives and Social Preferences
: Substitutes or
Complements?
Journal of Economic Literature
,
50
(2), 368
–
425.
https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.50.2.368
Brown, A. L., Chua, Z. E., & Camerer, C. F. (2009). Learning and visceral temptation in
dynamic saving
experiments.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
124
(1), 197
–
231.
Bruhin, A., Fehr, E., &
Schunk, D. (2019). The many Faces of Human Sociality: Uncovering the
Distribution and Stability of Social Preferences.
Journal of the European Economic Association
,
17
(4), 1025
–
1069. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeea/jvy018
Burt, R. S., & Ronchi, D. (2007). Teaching executives to see social capital: Results from a field
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
20
experiment.
Social Science Research
,
36
(3), 1156
–
1183.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ssresearch.2006.09.005
Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioural studies of strategic thinking in games.
Trends in Cognitive Sciences
,
7
(5), 225
–
231. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1364
-
6613(03)00094
-
9
Camerer, C., & Fehr,
E. (2004). Measuring Social Norms and Preferences Using Experimental Games: A
Guide for Social Scientists. In J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, & H. Gintis
(Eds.),
Foundations
of Human Sociality
. https://doi.org/10.1093/0199262055.001.0001
Camerer, C., & Ho, T. H. (1999). Experience
-
weighted Attraction Lea
rning in Normal Form Games.
Econometrica
,
67
(4), 827
–
874. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468
-
0262.00054
Camerer, C., Issacharoff, S., Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003
). Regulation for
Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for “Asymmetric Paternalism.”
University of
Pennsylvania Law Review
,
151
(3), 1211. https://doi.org/10.2307/3312889
Camerer, C., Loewens
tein, G., & Rabin, M. (Eds.). (2004).
Advances in behavioral economics
. New
York
: Princeton, N.J: Russell Sage Foundation
; Princet
on University Press.
Camerer, C., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Anomalies: Ultimatums, Dictators and Manners.
Journal of
Economic Perspect
ives
,
9
(2), 209
–
219. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.2.209
Camerer, C., & Weigelt, K. (1988). Experimental Tests of a Sequential Equilibrium Reputation Model.
Econometrica
,
56
(1), 1. https://doi.org/10.2307/1911840
Candelo, N., Eckel, C., & Johnson, C. (2018). Social Distance Matters in Dictator Games: Evidence from
11 Mexican Villages.
Games
,
9
(4), 77. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040077
Chetty, R., Friedman, J. N., Leth
-
Petersen, S., Nielsen, T. H., & Olsen, T. (2014). Active vs. Passive
Decisions and Crowd
-
Out in Retirement Savings Accounts: Evidence from Denmark *.
The
Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
129
(3), 1141
–
1219. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qju013
Christakis, N. A., & Fowler, J. H. (2011).
Connected: The surprising power of our social n
etworks and
how they shape our lives
. New York, NY: Little, Brown.
Cohn, A., Maréchal, M. A., Tannenbaum, D., & Zünd, C. L. (2019).
Civic honesty around the globe.
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
21
Science
,
365
(6448), 70
–
73. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aau8712
Coviello, L., Sohn, Y., Kramer, A. D. I., Marlow, C., Franceschetti, M., Christakis, N. A., &
Fowler, J. H.
(2014). Detecting Emotional Contagion in Massive Social Networks.
PLoS ONE
,
9
(3), e90315.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0090315
Davis, G. F., & Greve, H. R. (1997). Corporate Elite
Networks and Governance Changes in the 1980s.
American Journal of Sociology
,
103
(1), 1
–
37. https://doi.org/10.1086/231170
De Martino, B., Camerer, C. F., & Adolphs, R. (2010). Amygdala damage eliminate
s monetary loss
aversion.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
,
107
(8), 3788
–
3792.
DellaVigna, S. (2018). Structural Behavioral Economics. In
Handbook of Behavioral Economics:
Applications and Foundations 1
(Vol. 1, pp. 613
–
723).
https://doi.org/10.1016/bs.hesbe.2018.07.005
DellaVigna, S., List, J. A., & Malmendier, U. (2012). Testing for Altruism and Social Pressure in
Charitable Giving.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
127
(1), 1
–
56.
https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjr050
DellaVigna, S., & Pope, D. G. (2018). What Motivates Effort? Evidence and Expert Forecasts.
The
Review of Economic Studies
,
85
(2), 1029
–
1069. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdx033
Donaldson, D., & Hornbeck, R. (2016). Railroads and American Economic Growth: A “Market Access”
Approach.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
131
(2), 799
–
858.
https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjw002
Edgeworth, F. Y. (1881).
Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the
Moral Sciences
. Retriev
ed from https://books.google.com/books?id=StokAAAAMAAJ
Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Cooperation and Punishment in Public Goods Experiments.
American
Economic Review
,
90
(4), 980
–
994. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.4.980
Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., & Riedl, A. (1993). Does Fairness Prevent Market Clearing? An Experimental
Investigation.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
108
(2), 437
–
459.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2118338
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
22
Frank, M. R., Autor, D., Bessen, J. E., Brynjolfsson, E., Cebrian, M., Deming, D. J., ... Rahwan, I.
(2019). Toward understanding the impact of
artificial intelligence on labor.
Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences
,
116
(14), 6531
–
6539. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1900949116
Freeman, L. C. (2004).
The development of social network analysis: A study in the sociology of science
.
Vancouver, BC
: North Charleston, S.C: Empirical Press
; BookSurge.
Gintis, H. (2007). A framework for the unification of the behavioral sciences.
Behavioral and Brain
Sciences
,
30
(1), 1
–
16. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X07000581
Gintis, H., van Schaik, C., & Boehm, C. (2015). Zoon Politikon: The Evolutionary Origins of Human
Political Systems.
Current Anthropol
ogy
,
56
(3), 327
–
353. https://doi.org/10.1086/681217
Gneezy, U., & Potters, J. (1997). An experiment on risk taking and evaluation periods.
The Quarterly
Journal of Economics
,
112
(2), 631
–
645.
Goeree, J. K., McC
onnell, M. A., Mitchell, T., Tromp, T., & Yariv, L. (2010). The 1/d Law of Giving.
American Economic Journal: Microeconomics
,
2
(1), 183
–
203.
https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.2.1.183
Güth, W., Schmittberger,
R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining.
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
,
3
(4), 367
–
388. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167
-
2681(82)90011
-
7
Henrich, J., Bauer, M., Cassar, A., Chytilová, J., & Purzycki, B. G. (2019). War increases religiosity.
Nature Human Behaviour
,
3
(2), 129
–
135. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562
-
018
-
0512
-
3
Henrich, J., Boyd
, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., ... Tracer, D. (2005). “Economic
man” in cross
-
cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small
-
scale societies.
Behavioral and Brain S
ciences
,
28
(6), 795
–
815. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X05000142
Henrich, J., Ensminger, J., McElreath, R., Barr, A., Barrett, C., Bolyanatz, A., ... Ziker, J. (2010).
Markets, Religion, Community Size, and the Evolution of Fairness and Punishment.
Science
,
327
(5972), 14
80
–
1484. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1182238
Herrmann, B., Thoni, C., & Gächter, S. (2008). Antisocial Punishment Across Societies.
Science
,
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
23
319
(5868), 1362
–
1367. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1153808
Jackson, M. O. (2019).
The human network: How your social position determ
ines your power, beliefs,
and behaviors
(First edition). New York: Pantheon Books.
Jackson, M. O., & Wolinsky, A. (1996). A Strategi
c Model of Social and Economic Networks.
Journal of
Economic Theory
,
7
1
(1), 44
–
74. https://doi.org/10.1006/jeth.1996.0108
Johnson, E. J., & Goldstein, D. (2003). Do Defaults Save Lives?
Science
,
302
(5649), 1338
–
1339.
https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1091721
Johnson, E. J., Häubl, G., & Keinan, A. (2007). Aspects of endowment: A query theory of value
construction.
Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition
,
33
(3),
461
–
474. https://doi.org/10.1037/0278
-
7393.33.3.461
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., &
Thaler, R. H. (1990). Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and
the Coase Theorem.
Journal of Political Economy
,
98
(6), 1325
–
1348.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect Theory: An Analysis
of Decision under Risk.
Econometrica
,
47
(2), 263. https://doi.org/10.2307/1914185
Kanngiesser, P., Santos, L. R., Hood, B. M., & Call, J. (2011). The limits of endowment effects in great
apes (Pan panis
cus, Pan troglodytes, Gorilla gorilla, Pongo pygmaeus).
Journal of Comparative
Psychology
,
125
(4), 436
–
445. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0024516
Kermack, W. O., & McKendrick, A. G. (1927). A Contribution to
the Mathematical Theory of Epidemics.
Proceedings of the Royal Society A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences
,
115
(772),
700
–
721. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspa.1927.0118
Krajbich, I., Adolphs, R., Tranel, D., Denburg, N. L., & Camerer, C. (2009). Economic Games Quantify
Diminished Sense of Guilt in Patients with Damage to the Prefrontal Cortex.
Journal of
Neuros
cience
,
29
(7), 2188
–
2192. https://doi.org/10.1523/JNEUROSCI.5086
-
08.20
09
Kretzschmar, M., & Morris, M. (1996). Measures of concurrency in networks and the spread of infectious
disease.
Mathematical Bios
ciences
,
133
(2), 165
–
195. https://doi.org/10.1016/0025
-
5564(95)00093
-
3
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
24
Krupka, E., & Weber, R. A. (2009). The focusing and informational effects of norms on pro
-
social
behavior.
Journal of Economic Psyc
hology
,
30
(3), 307
–
320.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2008.11.005
Lakshminaryanan, V., Chen, M. K., & Santos, L. R. (2008). Endowment effect in capuchin monkeys.
Philosophical Transactions of the Royal
Society of London B: Biological Sciences
,
363
(1511),
3837
–
3844.
Legewie, J. (2016). Racial Profiling and Use of Force in Police Stops: How Local Events Trigger Periods
of Increased Discrimination.
A
merican Journal of Sociology
,
122
(2), 379
–
424.
https://doi.org/10.1086
/687518
Lerner, J. S., Small, D. A., & Loewenstein, G. (2004). Heart Strings and Purse Strings. Carryover Effects
of Emotions on Economic Decisions.
Psychological Science
,
15
(5), 337
–
341.
https://doi.or
g/10.1111/j.0956
-
7976.2004.00679.x
Loewenstein, G. F., Thompson, L., & Bazerman, M. H. (1989). Social utility and decision making in
interpersonal contexts.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology
,
57
(3), 426
–
441.
https://doi.org/10.1037/0022
-
3514.57.3.426
Magliocca, N. R., McSweeney, K., Sesnie, S. E., Tellman, E., Devine, J. A., Nielsen, E. A., ... Wrathall,
D. J. (2019). Modeling cocaine
traffickers and counterdrug interdiction forces as a complex
adaptive system.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
,
116
(16), 7784
–
7792.
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1812459116
Mas, A. (200
6). Pay, Reference Points, and Police Performance*.
Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
121
(3), 783
–
821. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.121.3.783
McDermott, R. (2004). Prospect Theory in Political Science: Ga
ins and Losses From the First Decade.
Political Psychology
,
25
(2), 289
–
312. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467
-
9221.2004.00372.x
Messick, D. M., & Cook, K. S. (Eds.). (1983).
Equity theory: Psychological and sociological
perspectives
. New York, N.Y: Praeger.
Messick, D. M., &
McClintock, C. G. (1968). Motivational bases of choice in experimental games.
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
25
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology
,
4
(1), 1
–
25. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022
-
1031(68)90046
-
2
Meyer, M. N., Heck, P. R., Holtzman, G. S., Anderson, S. M., Cai, W., Watts, D. J., & Chabris, C. F.
(2019). Objecting to experiments that compare two unobjectionable policies or treatments.
Pro
ceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
,
116
(22), 10723
–
10728.
ht
tps://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1820701116
Morelli, S. A., Ong, D. C., Makati, R., Jackson, M. O., & Zaki, J. (2017). Empathy and well
-
being
correlate with centrality in different social networks.
Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences
,
114
(37), 9843
–
9847. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1702155114
Morris, M., Goodreau, S., & Moody, J. (2008). Sexual Networks, Concurrency, and STD/HIV. In K.
K.
Holmes (Ed.),
Sexually transmitted diseases
(4th ed, pp. 109
–
125). New York: McGraw
-
Hill
Medical.
Morris, M., & Kretzschmar, M. (1997). Concurrent partnerships and the spread of HIV:
AIDS
,
11
(5),
641
–
648. https://doi.org/10.1097/00002030
-
199705000
-
00012
Muthukrishna, M
., & Schaller, M. (2019). Are Collectivistic Cultures More Prone to Rapid
Transformation? Computational Models of Cross
-
Cultural Differences, Social Network Structure,
Dynamic Social Influence, and Cultural Change.
Personality and Social Psychology Review
,
108886831985578. https://doi.org/10.1177/1088868319855783
Nave, G., Minxha, J., Greenberg, D. M., Kosinski, M., Stillwell, D., & Rentfrow, J. (2018). Musical
Preferences Predict Personality: Evidence From Active Listening and Facebook Likes.
Psychological Science
,
29
(7), 1145
–
1158. https://doi
.org/10.1177/0956797618761659
Payne, J. W., Sagara, N., Shu, S. B., Appelt, K. C., & Johnson, E. J. (2013). Life expectancy as a
constructed belief: Evidence of a live
-
to or die
-
by framing effec
t.
Journal of Risk and
Uncertainty
,
46
(1), 27
–
50.
Phan, T. Q., & Airoldi, E. M. (2015). A natural experiment of social network formation and dynamics.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
,
112
(21), 6
595
–
6600.
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314
26
https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1404770112
Philpot, R., Liebst, L. S., Levine, M., Bernasco, W., & Lindegaard, M. R. (2019). Would I be helped?
Cross
-
national CCTV footage shows that inte
rvention is the norm in public conflicts.
American
Psychologist
. https://doi.org/10.1037/amp0000469
Richerson, P. J., & Boyd, R. (1989). The role of evolved predispositions in cultural evolution.
Ethology
and Sociobiology
,
10
(1
–
3), 195
–
219. https://doi.org/10.1016/0162
-
3095(89)90019
-
8
Salganik, M. J. (2018).
Bit by bit: Social research in the digital age
. Princeton: Princ
eton University
Press.
Samuelson, W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1988). Status quo bias in decision making.
Journal of Risk and
Uncertainty
,
1
(1), 7
–
59. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00055564
Schweitzer, F., Fagiolo, G., Sornette, D., Vega
-
Redondo, F., Vespignani, A., & White, D. R. (2009).
Economic Networks: The New Challenges.
Science
,
325
(5939), 422
–
425.
https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1173644
Smith, A. (1759).
The Theory of Moral Sentiments
. McMaster University Archive for the History of
Economic Thought.
Suel, E., Polak, J. W., Bennett, J. E., & Ezzati, M. (2019). Measuring social, environmental and health
inequalities using deep
learning and street imagery.
Scientific Reports
,
9
(1), 6229.
https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598
-
019
-
42036
-
w
Thaler, R. H. (2015).
Misbehaving:
The making of behavioral economics
. Retrieved from
https://www.overdrive.com/search?q=F1484CE2
-
43BC
-
4DA9
-
A850
-
4279E96BFAF8
Thaler, R
. H. (2018). From Cashews to Nudges: The Evolution of Behavioral Economics.
American
Economic Review
,
108
(6), 1265
–
1287. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.108.6.1265
Thaler, R. H., & Benartzi, S. (2004). Save
More Tomorrow
TM
: Using Behavioral Economics to Increase
Employee Saving.
Journal of Political Economy
,
112
(S1), S164
–
S187.
https://doi.org/10.1086/380085
Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2009).
Nudge: Improving decisions about health, we
alth, and happiness
Electronic
copy
available
at
:
https
:
/
/
ssrn.com
/
abstract
=
3486314